Tom
gives an update on gerrymandering and the courts with, of course, some data.
Last week a panel of federal judges did something highly
unusual: they told the state of North
Carolina that the method they had used to draw congressional district lines exhibited “invidious
partisan intent” in maximizing the chances for Republican overrepresentation in
the U.S. House of Representatives, and literally sent them back to the drawing
board. The State Assembly, which
controls the process, was given three weeks to redraw those district lines in a
fairer way; the court said they, too, would prepare new districts, and
if the state failed a second time, the court would mandate the use of its own
method.
The courts have a long history of disliking gerrymandering. Like pornography, they “know it when they
see it” (as Justice Potter Stewart famously said), but, also like pornography,
they have trouble coming up with a standard by which to determine when it has
crossed the line to become “unconstitutional.” After all, simply drawing equal-sized circles
will not ensure that each district has roughly 711,000 voters in it (the U.S. population
as of the 2010 Census divided by the number of seats in the House), and it is,
of course, very common for like-minded people to live near each other. So determining which districts have been
drawn in a biased manner is not an easy exercise.
But the North Carolinians made it easy on the courts. In what amounts to an admission of guilt, North
Carolina redistricting chief Rep. David Lewis stated the following: "I think
electing Republicans is better than electing Democrats. So I drew this map to
help foster what I think is better for the country." And when asked why he drew the map with the
goal of the GOP winning 10 of the state’s 13 districts – obviously unbalanced in this true "battleground" state -- Lewis said "because I do not believe it's possible to draw a map with 11 Republicans and two Democrats." Willy Sutton could not have given a more direct and damning reply. (Sutton is the gentleman who, when asked why he robbed banks for a living, said with disarming clarity "because that's where the money is.")
Let’s illustrate this “invidious
partisanship” with some numbers and maps.
The chart below shows that, overall (the purple line), in North Carolina the GOP totaled 2.4
million statewide votes across 13 elections for the House in 2016, while the
Dems garnered 2.1 million votes, a relatively close 53% to 47% margin. Had House seats been apportioned simply on
this overall vote, the GOP would have earned seven seats to the Democrats’ six. But because the map was drawn so cleverly, to
maximize each GOP vote and minimize each Dem vote, those Dem votes were largely
shoved into three districts, the 1st, 4th and 12th,
where the Dems won handily, siphoning off votes from the other districts, which
the GOP won, also handily.
2016 Votes (000)
|
2016 Vote %
|
|||
NC District
|
GOP
|
DEM
|
GOP
|
DEM
|
1
|
101
|
238
|
29%
|
69%
|
2
|
219
|
167
|
57%
|
43%
|
3
|
215
|
104
|
67%
|
33%
|
4
|
128
|
276
|
32%
|
68%
|
5
|
205
|
146
|
58%
|
42%
|
6
|
206
|
141
|
59%
|
41%
|
7
|
210
|
134
|
61%
|
39%
|
8
|
188
|
131
|
59%
|
41%
|
9
|
192
|
137
|
58%
|
42%
|
10
|
220
|
128
|
63%
|
37%
|
11
|
229
|
128
|
64%
|
36%
|
12
|
114
|
232
|
33%
|
67%
|
13
|
197
|
154
|
56%
|
44%
|
Total State
|
2,424
|
2,116
|
53%
|
47%
|
And the map below shows how they did it. By stringing together a collection of Dem
strongholds (in blue) with true “salamander” creativity, the GOP strengthened
their neighboring districts. (‘Gerrymandering”
is, of course, a portmanteau of its original inventor, Massachusetts Governor and
Founding Father Elbridge Gerry, and the salamander-esque district shapes he was
fond of creating to favor his party.)
So: Democratic
voters in North Carolina have been cheated out of fair representation in
violation of their First Amendment rights, according to federal judges. We will find out how much representation soon enough, but below is a “hypothetical”
outcome based on a “fairer” map, in which the Dems would have picked up at
least two more seats and possibly a few more.
No salamanders in this map.
Of even greater import regarding gerrymandering is the case before the Supreme Court, which will be decided in this Court term, and likely announced in late June when all the major cases are usually decided. The Court has already heard oral arguments (last October) in gerrymandering cases brought by Democrats in Wisconsin and Pennsylvania (the cases have been combined) that involve gerrymandering at the state legislature level, in which the GOP has secured outrageous majorities beyond realistic hope of ever bring “flipped.”
The Court has taken the case because a standard has been
introduced to guide determination of whether or not there is gerrymandering –
the “holy grail” of gerrymandering opponents.
If they can convince the Court of the validity of the standard, then the
Court will rule in favor of the Democrats, and maps nationwide will have to be
reassessed against this standard.
What is this mystical standard? It is called “The Efficiency Gap” and it a
mathematically-based calculation that exposes, essentially, how gerrymandered
states waste more votes for the
aggrieved party. Here is the explanation
of it, by its creator, a professor of the University of Chicago named Nicholas
Stephanopoulos (no relation to George).
“The efficiency gap is simply the difference between the parties’
respective wasted votes in an election,
divided by the total number of votes cast. Wasted votes are ballots that don’t
contribute to victory for candidates, and they come in two forms: lost
votes cast for candidates who are defeated, and surplus votes cast
for winning candidates but in excess of what they needed to prevail. When a
party gerrymanders a state, it tries to maximize the wasted votes for the
opposing party while minimizing its own, thus producing a large efficiency gap.
In a state with perfect
partisan symmetry, both parties would have the same number of wasted votes.
Suppose, for example, that a state has five districts with 100 voters
each, and two parties, Party A and Party B. Suppose also that Party A wins four
of the seats 53 to 47, and Party B wins one of them 85 to 15. Then in each of
the four seats that Party A wins, it has 2 surplus votes (53 minus the 51
needed to win), and Party B has 47 lost votes. And in the lone district that
Party A loses, it has 15 lost votes, and Party B has 34 surplus votes (85 minus
the 51 needed to win). In sum, Party A wastes 23 votes and Party B wastes 222
votes. Subtracting one figure from the other and dividing by the 500 votes cast
produces an efficiency gap of 40 percent in Party A’s favor.”
I ran the numbers in North Carolina and, as it
turns out, in the 2016 House election North Carolina had a 39% efficiency gap
in the GOP’s favor, nearly identical to the gap found by Stephanopoulos in his
hypothetical example.
Veteran court watchers believe that, once
again, this could all come down to the ubiquitous swing Justice Anthony Kennedy. Kennedy wrote over a decade ago that he
believed gerrymandering was unconstitutional under the First Amendment, and, in
the oral arguments, his questioning of the defendants seemed pretty tough. But it will all come down to whether he finds
the “Efficiency Gap” standard to be persuasive.
If he does, and is joined by the liberal
wings of the Court (as expected) the Court will thus overturn the Wisconsin and
Pennsylvania schemes. However, they may
not enforce a remedy there or anywhere in time for the midterms. They could peg it to the normal redistricting
efforts that occurs after the next Census, which would be in 2020.
In addition, note that the GOP lead in the
House cannot be attributed solely to gerrymandering. But there is little doubt that, because of
many states like North Carolina, such a verdict would be welcome news for the
Democrats and would have a material favorable impact on their electoral hopes. In the meantime, we’ll see what happens in
North Carolina on January 24 when the Assembly returns with their
new map.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Leave a comment